Mises Wire

Do Inflationary Expectations Cause General Increases in Prices?

Inflation expectations

Many believe the key cause to a general increase in prices are so-called “inflationary expectations.” For instance, if there is a large increase in the prices of oil, individuals will start forming expectations for higher inflation ahead. Consequently, individuals will speed up their purchases of goods and services at present, thereby raising the demand for goods and services, all other things being equal. This is supposed to set in motion general price increases. According to the former Fed Chairman Ben Bernanke, “Undoubtedly, the state of inflation expectations greatly influences actual inflation and thus the central bank’s ability to achieve price stability.”

It is believed that, if inflationary expectations could be made less responsive to various shocks, then, over time, this would mitigate the effects of these shocks on the momentum of the prices of goods and services. Most commentators believe central bank policies can be employed to bring individuals’ inflationary expectations to a state of equilibrium. At this state of equilibrium, it is believed, expectations can be anchored in order to not be as sensitive to changes in various economic data. Once inflationary expectations are anchored, various shocks—such as a large increase in the price of oil or food—are likely to have a short-lived effect on general price increases. According to Bernanke, anchoring inflation expectations is of utmost importance to eradicate inflation,

…the latest round of increases in energy prices has added to the upside risks to inflation and inflation expectations. The Federal Open Market Committee will strongly resist an erosion of longer-term inflation expectations, as an unanchoring of those expectations would be destabilizing for growth as well as for inflation.

Note that what matters, according to this view, is underlying price increases. Because of this, Federal Reserve policymakers and many economists are of the view that, in order to track the underlying price increases—labeled as inflation—one must pay attention to the core inflation. Core inflation has to do with percentage changes in the consumer price index.

Allegedly, to make inflation expectations well-anchored, individuals must be clear about the monetary policy of central bank policymakers. For most commentators, through inflation targeting and clear communication by policymakers, the central bank can make inflationary expectations “well-anchored” (i.e., not sensitive to data changes).

Can general increases in prices happen without the increase in money supply?

According to mainstream thinking, a change in the price of a commodity, such as oil, can set in motion persistent inflation. It is believed that the emergence of inflation in response to the increase in the price of oil requires increases in expected inflation. Ben Bernanke is of the view that, “...a one-off change in energy prices can translate into persistent inflation only if it leads to higher expected inflation and a consequent ‘wage-price spiral.’”

However, without the preceding increases in money supply, all other things being equal, there cannot be a general increase in prices, which is often labeled “inflation.” A price of a good is the amount of dollars paid per unit of a good (in a money economy using dollars). Hence, for a given quantity of goods, if the stock of money remains unchanged the amount of dollars employed per unit of a good will also remain unchanged, all other things being equal.

Let us say, for example, that because of a strong increase in the price of oil, individuals have raised their inflationary expectations. If the money stock remains unchanged, then no general increase in the prices of goods and services is going to take place, notwithstanding the increase in inflationary expectations. If more money is spent on oil and energy related products, less money will be left for other goods and services. All that will happen is that the prices of oil and energy-related goods will go up while the prices of other goods and services will go down.

It is increases in the money supply that underpin the underlying rises in prices, and not inflationary expectations. Without the support from money supply, all other things being equal, no general increase in prices can take place notwithstanding inflationary expectations. Furthermore, what matters as far as inflation is concerned is not its manifestation in terms of increases in the prices of goods and services, but the damage it inflicts to the wealth-generation process. Increases in money supply—which is inflation—sets in motion an exchange of nothing for something and distorts and price and production structure. This diverts wealth from wealth-generators to non-wealth-generators.

Some economists, such as Milton Friedman, maintain that if price inflation is “expected” by producers and consumers, then it causes very little damage (see Friedman’s Dollars and Deficits, pp. 47-48). The problem, according to Friedman, is with unexpected price inflation, which causes a misallocation of resources and weakens the economy. According to Friedman, if a general rise in prices could be stabilized through a fixed rate of monetary injections, individuals would then adjust their conduct accordingly. Consequently, Friedman held, expected general price increases—which he labeled expected inflation—would be harmless, with no real effect. Friedman regards the money supply as a policy tool that can stabilize general increases in prices, thereby promoting economic growth. According to this way of thinking, all that is required is fixing the money growth rate at some percentage. The rest will follow suit!

The fixing of the money supply’s growth rate at a certain expected percentage does not alter the fact that money supply continues to expand. It will lead to the diversion of resources and distortion of the price and production structure, reduce purchasing power, and produce business cycles. Hence, the policy of stabilizing prices will generate more instability!

Contrary to popular thinking, inflation is not about increases in prices, but about increases in money supply. Also contrary to various commentators, inflationary expectations—in the absence of increases in money supply—cannot cause a general increase in the prices of goods and services.

image/svg+xml
Image Source: Adobe Stock
Note: The views expressed on Mises.org are not necessarily those of the Mises Institute.
What is the Mises Institute?

The Mises Institute is a non-profit organization that exists to promote teaching and research in the Austrian School of economics, individual freedom, honest history, and international peace, in the tradition of Ludwig von Mises and Murray N. Rothbard. 

Non-political, non-partisan, and non-PC, we advocate a radical shift in the intellectual climate, away from statism and toward a private property order. We believe that our foundational ideas are of permanent value, and oppose all efforts at compromise, sellout, and amalgamation of these ideas with fashionable political, cultural, and social doctrines inimical to their spirit.

Become a Member
Mises Institute