Mises Wire

Demystifying Tariffs

Mystery

In February 2025, President Trump implemented an extra 25 percent tariff on imports from Canada and Mexico and a 10 percent tariff on imports from China, which doubled to 20 percent last week. There’s also a 10 percent tariff on energy resources from Canada. This is significant as goods from China, Mexico and Canada accounted for more than 40 percent of imports into the US in 2024. On March 11, 2025, the uncertain climate led many investors to withdraw from tariffed sectors with elastic demand, causing a US stock market decline. So let’s cut to the chase and analyse how tariffs work, how effective or counter-effective they are, their historic trend and their similarity to subsidies.

Tariff vs. Free Trade

A free market operates on Ricardo’s principle of comparative advantage, where trade exists because no country is self-sufficient. Countries either lack resources (e.g., India importing crude from the Middle East), infrastructure (e.g., the US importing pharmaceuticals from India), or expertise (e.g., the US and China importing electronic chips from Taiwan). Countries should specialize in producing goods and services with lower opportunity costs and export them, while freely importing others. This leads to better quality and lower costs for consumers.

Support for free trade—a key pillar of the free market—peaked during the globalization era after the WTO’s formation in 1995. However, governments often intervene by imposing tariffs, which are taxes on imports. Alongside quotas, tariffs are significant trade barriers, increasing prices for consumers and forcing them to buy costlier domestic products if demand is inelastic. This is part of a wider subject of Foreign Trade Policy.

Causes & Effects of Tariffs on the Importing Country

In the short term, tariffs reduce imports, boost domestic production, and raise costs of inputs and contribute to increases of consumer prices. This is illustrated by the demand-supply curve (Fig. 1). As domestic consumers buy less and domestic producers supply more, imports decrease. The graph shows overproduction and underconsumption losses, together representing the Dead-Weight Loss (DWL) in the economy.

Tariffs exacerbate inflation, reducing disposable income, especially for lower-income groups, making them a regressive tax. This increases demand for government spending and makes people more dependent on the government. Inflation is more pronounced when tariffs are applied to intermediate capital goods like steel, semiconductors, and fabric, which make up two-thirds of world trade. Cascading tax effects and profit margins at each level magnify price distortions down the supply chain.

Figure 1

The Infant Industry Argument

In the long-term, tariffs apparently protect domestic manufacturers from global competition. This protectionism is often politicized, ensuring employment and pleasing local interest groups, supposedly aiding industrialization in infant sectors of developing economies. 

However, I disagree due to protectionism’s unseen costs which was brought out in Frederic Bastiat’s 1845 essay “Candlemakers’ Petition,” where he satirized candlemakers seeking protection from foreign competition. He argued that candlemakers are not advocating for the welfare of the French people, but rather for their own self-interest. By reducing competition, efficiency, and innovation in protected domestic industries, we have cronyism, lobbyism, and global overcapacity.

This creates a dichotomy with protected firms lacking incentives to improve, while the free-market firms struggle. Furceri et al. (2019) found that increased tariffs result in a 0.4 percent decline in output growth over five years.

Negating the employment claim, the US Steel Tariff of 2018 led to invisible job losses of around 75,000 and deadweight losses in downstream sectors, contrasting with 1,000 new visible steel jobs—each costing US customers $900,000—as per one study.

National Security Argument

Another long-term objective of tariffs is national security, aiming to make countries self-reliant in critical sectors like semiconductors and energy, or to diversify trade supply chains. This argument gained traction due to over-reliance on China, highlighted by rising labor costs (Fig. 2), the US-China Trade War 2018, and supply chain failures during China’s Zero Covid policy 2020. Countries began decoupling from China, moving manufacturing to Vietnam and India (friendshoring) under the China+1 approach. However, this involved logistical challenges.

Figure 2

Moreover, China has rerouted products to the US through backdoor third countries like Mexico and Vietnam (Fig. 3), where it invests heavily in greenfield projects. For instance, much of the value addition for telecom equipment occurs in China, with final assembly in Vietnam by Chinese companies before export to the US.

Figure 3

To contain that, the US is also targeting Mexico, Vietnam, and Canada, pressuring them to impose tariffs on China. Canada’s tariffs on China recently led to counter-tariffs. A global tariff chain like this could endanger free trade.

While national security and supply chain diversification are reasonable long-term goals, tariffs aren’t the optimal means. Stockpiling strategic resources like petroleum or rare earth minerals is still more efficient than creating inefficient domestic industries. Protectionism fosters lobbyism, diverting resources from innovation to seeking protection.

Protectionism fails miserably in innovative industries vital for national security like AI or supercomputers, which thrive on open competition, as we saw recently in Deepseek upending the AI industry. You may also recall that despite US tariffs on foreign cars in the 1970s-80s, Japanese and German automakers outperformed US companies by innovating better, more fuel-efficient cars. Free trade also reduces geopolitical tensions, as countries that trade heavily rarely go to war, as Richard Rosecrance postulated.

Are Retaliatory Tariffs Justified?

Trade deficits are one reason given for imposing tariffs. But trade deficits create American jobs by funding otherwise unfunded domestic investment with offshore savings. Moreover, relatively low merchandise exports by the US as compared to Germany or China is not just due to foreign tariffs but also supply-side constraints within the US which discourage economies of scale. Further, a trade imbalance demonstrates many voluntary exchanges.

Again, trade-distorting subsidies are often used to justify retaliatory tariffs, as seen when the US and EU imposed tariffs on Chinese EVs (100 percent) and batteries (25 percent) last year. Suppose those retaliatory tariffs were never enacted. Then, following the argument of Milton Friedman, the Chinese would have sold more EVs and utilized the earned dollars to buy goods and services, either from the US or other nations, thereby re-investing back in the US.

Historic Trend of Tariffs

During the late 19th century Gilded Age in the US, certain sectors protected by high tariffs—like textiles and chemicals—showed low productivity and struggled, while sectors exposed to international competition, like electrical machinery, innovated and excelled.

The Smoot-Hawley Tariff Act of 1930—widely seen as worsening the Great Depression—finally led to a sharp abandonment of tariff policies in the US until 2018 (Fig. 4).

Figure 4

Post-WWII, newly-independent nations in Asia, Africa, and Latin America adopted Keynesian and Institutional Economics, Dependency Theory, and Import Substitution Industrialization to reduce dependence on former colonial powers. Larger countries like India and China placed their domestic markets behind a tariff wall, while smaller nations like South Korea and Singapore pursued export-led growth through free trade, achieving rapid success.

These post-colonial states initially thrived on consumption-led growth and primary goods exports, but the Prebisch-Singer thesis predicts a “resource curse,” leading to adverse terms of trade and balance of payments crises. This stimulated both liberalization reforms and import substitution, resulting in their presently high tariffs (Fig. 5).

Figure 5

This affects development, for example in India, where the current average tariff is around 15 percent—a protectionist closed economy in key manufacturing sectors led to an early shift to the service sector in the 1980s, which was less inclusive for job creation and contributed to income inequality. Tariffs maintain societal divisions, undermining their intended purpose.

Subsidy vs. Tariff

Some view domestic subsidies as a better alternative to tariffs, but both are forms of protectionism that create inefficiencies and interfere with free market dynamics. Consumers either bear the cost through higher taxes (subsidies) or prices (tariffs).

Subsidies—like tariffs—can lead to trade wars. For instance, EU’s CAP subsidies have protected European farmers but caused overproduction and trade disputes. Similarly, the US and EU have long disputed each other’s subsidies to Boeing and Airbus.

Finally, subsidies are often given to a company in a bid to offset the losses it has incurred due to tariffs, infrastructure gaps, and regulatory hurdles. But it’s like one wrong to cover up another wrong, by burdening those taxpayers who may never benefit from these subsidized products.

Conclusion

So the final question is: Are tariffs any good at all, at least when they’re targeted? I would answer by quoting Milton Friedman’s excerpt from his speech at the University of Utah in 1978 when he exposed the unreasonableness of steel tariffs:

You know you could have a great employment in the city of Logan, Utah, of people growing bananas in hot houses. If we had a high enough tariff on the import of bananas, it could become profitable to build hot houses and grow bananas in hot houses. That would give employment. Would that be a sensible thing to do? If that isn’t sensible then neither is it sensible to artificially restrict the import of steel.

image/svg+xml
Image Source: Adobe Stock
Note: The views expressed on Mises.org are not necessarily those of the Mises Institute.
What is the Mises Institute?

The Mises Institute is a non-profit organization that exists to promote teaching and research in the Austrian School of economics, individual freedom, honest history, and international peace, in the tradition of Ludwig von Mises and Murray N. Rothbard. 

Non-political, non-partisan, and non-PC, we advocate a radical shift in the intellectual climate, away from statism and toward a private property order. We believe that our foundational ideas are of permanent value, and oppose all efforts at compromise, sellout, and amalgamation of these ideas with fashionable political, cultural, and social doctrines inimical to their spirit.

Become a Member
Mises Institute